Starting the Lawnmower

Starting the Lawnmower

Have you ever tried to start an old lawnmower?

If you haven’t, I bet you’ve at least watched someone struggle with it.

You yank on the starter cord with all your might and…nothing happens. You try it again…still nothing. After a few more tries, you’re sweaty and frustrated. But the grass still needs cutting.

You keep trying.

Three more pulls. Still nothing. You curse and kick the mower.

What’s wrong? Are you not pulling hard enough? Are you not strong enough? Or, is something else wrong?

Next time, you pull the cord and the motor fires. But, just briefly. It quickly stutters out again. Progress of a kind.

Finally, you realize that there’s not enough gas in the tank. Once you top it off, a few more pulls and you’re mowing grass!

This is what starting a company is like. Except slower.

With a startup, each pull of the starter cord is equally tiring. But, each pull can take weeks.

You don’t know how many pulls are going to be needed. You don’t know if it’s ever going to start working.

You just have to keep pulling, and keep tweaking things. Just like the mower, sometimes it will start but then, quickly stop again. It’s just as frustrating but for much longer.

This is why founders need grit to keep pulling. They also need smarts to work out why it’s not working.

But, there’s a better way than struggling alone. What if you had an experienced team to help? A team of lawnmower experts who were there to check there’s enough gas in the tank, to top it off if there isn’t, to make sure the spark plug is not fouled, to make sure the blade is adjusted correctly, or just grab the cord and pull with you.

That’s what a Venture Studio does. A Venture Studio helps you start the lawnmower so you can start mowing.

At Platform Venture Studio, we’re helping the next generation of entrepreneurs start their lawnmowers. If you’ve ever thought about being a startup founder yourself, or just want to checkout the companies we’re building, please consider joining Platform.

Everything You Always Wanted to Know about Unit Economics but were Afraid to Ask – Part 2

Everything You Always Wanted to Know about Unit Economics but were Afraid to Ask – Part 2

This is Part 2 of “Everything You Always Wanted to Know about Unit Economics but were Afraid to Ask”.  

This part covers the Unit Economics of Two-sided Marketplaces.  If you need an introduction (or refresher) on Unit Economics, please read Part 1 first.

Definition

Firstly, let’s define two-sided marketplaces:  these are businesses that make money by connecting Supply with Demand.  Examples are Wonolo, Uber, eBay, and Airbnb.

Sometimes, which side is “Supply” versus “Demand” can be counterintuitive.  To make it simple, Demand is normally the side that pays the money.  The marketplace business collects that money, takes out its slice, and passes the rest of the money to the Supply side.

At Wonolo, our “Supply” is our Wonoloers (the workers who do the job) and our “Demand” is our customers (companies that pay money to have the work done).

For Uber’s core business, riders are the “Demand”, and “Supply” are the drivers and their cars.  For Airbnb, “Demand” are guests and “Supply” are hosts with properties.

Unit Economics

Unit Economics get tricky in two-sided marketplaces because you have to consider both Demand and Supply.

To start with, you have two acquisition funnels, two CACs, two LTVs, two Break-even Points, etc.  You also have marketplace effects to consider.

This provides for a number of possible approaches to understanding Unit Economics:

  • model Supply and Demand in isolation,
  • model the Demand side as your “unit”, and consider Supply-side costs as variable costs,
  • model your Supply side as your “unit”, and consider Demand-side costs as variable costs, or
  • combine Supply and Demand and model at the individual interaction level – e.g. your unit is a job (Wonolo), ride (Uber), or stay (Airbnb).

In practice, you will often end up doing all of the above to provide multiple perspectives to investors.

However, for simplicity, my strong recommendation is that you start with modeling your Demand side as your “unit”.  I find that this is the most intuitive for most cases.  It most closely resembles the modeling of Unit Economics for simpler SaaS businesses, which are what most investors are familiar with.

Extra Layers of Complexity

In addition to considering how to model Supply and Demand, many marketplace businesses have additional complexities which make their Unit Economics even harder to model.

These complexities are not unique to marketplaces but are seen in many of them:

  • Variable spend: unlike a simple SaaS business, where customers sign-up and pay a fixed amount each month (MRR), marketplace users can have highly variable spend month-to-month. This has large impacts on LTV and break-even, and can make averages misleading.
  • Variable pricing: often the fee that customers pay is negotiated and/or variable, meaning margin is variable.
  • Seasonality: if a business is seasonal, it means the Break-even Point depends on when in the year a customer signs-up. This makes it hard to compare cohorts.
  • Ambiguous churn: for a simple SaaS business, customers sign up and then pay every month until they explicitly cancel their service. In contrast, many marketplaces only make money when supply and demand transact. Either or both sides can go dormant at any time and then come back at any time. This makes modeling churn hard and churn is a big determinant for LTV.

There are various ways to cut through these complexities, including comparing cohorts of like customers, and seasonal adjustments, but I’ll save those for a potential Part 3.

Marketplace Example: Wonolo

Since Wonolo is a business I’m intimately familiar with, I’m going to use it as my example.  However, the concepts here will be very similar for any two-sided marketplace.

Note: the numbers I’m using here are for illustrative purposes only, and to make for simple math. Several details that have a smaller impact on the numbers are omitted for simplicity.

Demand-side

Per the above, we’re going to model our Demand-side first.

Demand-side CAC

At Wonolo, our demand side is our customers. A typical customer is a logistics company with a warehouse needing Wonoloers (workers) to work on their production line.

The primary components of our Demand-side CAC are marketing and sales.

For illustrative purposes, let’s say the marketing component is $1,000 and the sales component is $4,000, making a total Demand-side CAC of $5,000.  (Remember that these are averages and can vary widely.)

Jobs

Our unit of interaction in our marketplace is the job. e.g. an 8 hour shift in a warehouse.

Length of shift and the hourly pay rate vary but, on average, let’s say a shift pays $100 and the average fee to our customer is 50%.

So, for each job, we charge the customer $150. We pass $100 straight on to the Wonoloer who did the job, leaving us with $50.*

Wonolo Job Economics

Combining this with the CAC above, we can see that it will take the customer using Wonolo for 100 jobs to pay back our Demand-side CAC [$5,000 / $50].  This gives us some sense, but not a full picture, since it doesn’t include the time dimension or the Supply side.

*Staffing companies typically lead with their Gross Revenue, which includes the wages to be paid to the worker. I think this is a misleading “vanity metric” because the wages are simply passed through. At Wonolo, we lead with Net Revenue.

Demand-side Break-even Point

So, we know that it takes 100 jobs to recoup our Demand-side CAC.  But, we don’t know how long that takes.  

To calculate that, we have to know how frequently our customers use our service – frequency of interaction (also referred to as “frequency of transaction”).

Let’s say that, on average, our customers post 2 jobs (shifts) per day.  We therefore now know that we recoup our Demand Side CAC after 50 days usage [100 / 2 = 50].

We also know that we hit our CAC-Doubling Point at twice this – 100 days.

Customer Lifetime & LTV

The next question we need to ask is whether we keep customers for at least 50 days. If we don’t, then we lose them before we pay back our Demand-side CAC, and our Unit Economics are negative.

Good news: we keep an average customer for 500 days.  Easily long enough to recoup our Demand-side CAC.

We can also now calculate our Customer Lifetime Value (LTV).  2 shifts per day, at $50 per shift, for 500 days, is an average LTV of $50,000 [2 x $50 x 500].

Supply Side

So far, we haven’t considered the Supply side – in Wonolo’s case, our Wonoloers (workers).

In this approach, we’re going to model the Supply-side costs as Variable Costs incurred in delivering our service to our Demand side (customers).

How much Supply is needed?

The first question to answer is, how much Supply do we need to satisfy our Demand?

In Wonolo’s case – and since the “unit” we’re modeling is our Customer – the question is, how many Wonoloers do we need to do the work one Customer needs done?

The first answer might be to say we need one Wonoloer per shift.  However, Wonoloers work multiple times for the same customer, so we don’t need nearly that many.

It turns out that, on average, a Wonoloer works for a given customer 10 times.  So we only need 1 Wonoloer for every 10 jobs that our Customer needs done.

Supply-side CAC

Now we need to consider how much it costs us to acquire a Wonoloer.

There are two primary elements here:  marketing cost (to get them to download the Wonolo app) and onboarding costs (to get them ready to work).

These costs add up to around $50 to find a Wonoloer and get them ready to do their first job.  i.e. our Supply-side CAC is $50.

Impact of Supply-side CAC on Demand Side

Now we know how much Supply we need to satisfy a customer’s demand, and we know how much that Supply costs, we can put it all together.

For convenience, let’s look at a year. 

Over the course of a year, a customer will use us for about 730 jobs on average [2 jobs per day for ~365 days]. 

So, on average, we’ll need 73 Wonoloers to meet that demand [730 / 10], and it’ll cost us $3,650 to acquire them [73 x $50].

Let’s look at how that impacts our overall unit economics calculations.

One approach is to look at the individual job level.  It costs $3,650 to get the supply for our customer’s 730 jobs per year.  So, per job, it costs us $5 to acquire the needed supply (Wonoloers) [$3,650 / 730 = $5].

Remember that we receive about $50 per job as our fee; so this means we’re spending 10% of that on Supply Acquisition.

So, rather than receiving the full $50 per job to pay back our Demand-side CAC, we’re netting $45 per job.  This pushes back our Break-even Point by a corresponding amount.  It takes us 111 days to hit breakeven on our $5,000 Demand-side CAC, once we’ve taken account of our Supply side costs [$5,000 / $45 = 111].

Given that we’re viewing the Supply side acquisition costs as variable costs, we can also say that our Contribution Margin of our staffing business is $45 per job and our Contribution Margin Ratio is 1.11 [$50 / ($50 – $5)].  

Marketplace Dynamics

So, good news:  it looks as if our business has positive unit economics!  We break-even on a per customer basis after 111 days on average, even taking into account the cost of finding the needed Supply (Wonoloers).

However, because we’re looking only at one customer in isolation, this entirely misses the fact that Wonolo is a marketplace.  These marketplace dynamics actually make the unit economics significantly better.  This is one way in which marketplaces can be extremely powerful.

Remember we said that, on average, a Wonoloer works for a given Customer 10 times?  That’s true but Wonoloers work at more than one Customer!  It turns out that Wonoloers work on average for 10 different Customers during their lifetime on Wonolo.

Therefore, we share our Supply-side acquisition costs across multiple Customers. 

This means we can divide the $5 per job that we spend by 10, meaning we only really spend 50 cents on average acquiring the needed Supply for one job [$5 / 10].

This means our Contribution Margin is actually $49.50 per job.

These marketplace dynamics exist in most marketplaces – arguably, that’s the point of the marketplace. Uber drivers don’t just drive one person, eBay sellers don’t just sell to one buyer, Airbnb hosts don’t just have one guest.  The ability to “sell” the same Supply to multiple Demand is what makes a marketplace powerful.

Ignored Components

As I said at the outset, I’ve ignored some components of Wonolo’s unit economics that would be included in any full accounting. These would include items such as:

  • customer account management,
  • customer and Wonoloer support, and
  • payment network and banking fees to collect payments from customers and pay Wonoloers.

Negative Unit Economics and The Big Gamble

Everything I’ve described above discusses Unit Economics in a sober and rational way; which is often not the way Silicon Valley works.  

There are several high-profile cases where companies have continued to grow aggressively despite clearly having negative unit economics.  The poster-child arguably being Uber.  At the time of writing (July 2020), despite its huge scale (meaning you’d expect its contribution margins would start to cover its fixed costs), Uber has never made a profit.  Will it ever? We’ll see.

To continue to grow despite having negative unit economics, businesses have to continue to raise bigger and bigger gobs of money.  Remember: negative unit economics means the more money you spend, the more money you lose.  Uber raised a total of $24.5B, including over $9B in their Series G alone.

Investors in Uber are continuing to make a big gamble that there will only be one or two winners, and the winners will be those that capture as much of the market as possible, even if it is done at a massive loss.  The thesis is that, once they’ve “won”, they’ll be able to keep out competition and control pricing to the extent that they can become profitable in the long-term.*

Investors are also gambling that Uber will be able to continue to raise money to cover the growing losses.  Fortunately for them, their market timing was good and they were able to continue to raise bigger and bigger rounds at higher and higher valuations before IPO.  If they were trying to raise that Series G today, it would likely be a very different story.

*This thesis is itself based on a perhaps flawed understanding of the strength of Uber’s network effects, but that’s a topic for another day…

 

Everything You Always Wanted to Know about Unit Economics but were Afraid to Ask – Part 1

Everything You Always Wanted to Know about Unit Economics but were Afraid to Ask – Part 1

Unit economics are critical to successful business growth.  Without positive unit economics, spending more money means you simply lose more money.

However, when it comes to two-sided marketplaces, It’s Complicated™.  I’ve seen experienced analysts admit defeat when trying to get to grips with our unit economics at Wonolo.

Here I aim to walk you through the topic step-by-step, in two parts.  No prior knowledge is assumed.

Part 1:  Unit Economics Basics

I want to provide a gentle learning curve.  Before we talk about two-sided marketplaces in Part 2, let’s first quickly cover some basics.  If (like me) you don’t have a formal background in finance, you may struggle with some of the terms used.

Disclaimer: because I’m assuming no prior knowledge, some complexities are overlooked for simplicity.

If you already know all this, feel free to skip straight to Part 2: Unit Economics in Two-Sided Marketplaces.

What’s a “unit”?

Ok, we’re talking about “unit economics”; so, what’s a unit?

For me, the confusion starts right here.  As the name implies, a “unit” might originally have referred to a widget made in a factory.  For example, if we run a factory that makes paperclips, unit economics relates to understanding the economics of paperclip production and sales, down to the level of an individual paperclip.

However, in the context of startups, we typically have one product and we’re selling access to that product.  The “unit” we’re interested in modeling is the act of selling access to a user or customer.

Therefore, a “unit” is typically equivalent to a customer or user.  As we run through these basics, you can think of our “unit” as a customer.

Variable vs Fixed Costs

The first core concept to understand is the distinction between “Variable” and “Fixed” costs.

Simply put:

  • Fixed Costs” remain the same, however much you sell.
  • Variable Costs” vary depending on how much you sell.  If you sell nothing, Variable Costs are zero.

When looking at Unit Economics, we’ll mostly be interested in Variable Costs.


Introducing our Lemonade Stand

I’m going to use a Lemonade Stand as an analogy.  It’s a simple but sometimes flawed analogy. (If nothing else, it presents an opportunity for some heart-warming pictures.)

For our lemonade stand:

    • Fixed Costs” would be the costs of renting and operating our lemonade stand, and the pay for the person running the stand.  They stay the same whether you sell 100 cups of lemonade or 0 cups.  (Ok, I wouldn’t normally pay my kids to run a lemonade stand but this is just an analogy.)
    • Variable Costs” would be the costs of the lemons, sugar, and water to make the lemonade.  They vary with how much lemonade you sell.

Customer Acquisition Cost (“CAC”)

The first of many TLAs (Three Letter Acronyms) is “CAC” or Customer Acquisition Cost.  This is what it costs you to acquire one customer.

The most obvious and common costs included in CAC are marketing costs.  

There are various accounting practices and standards that determine what else is or isn’t included in CAC.  For example, in some cases, CAC may include all or some part of the compensation paid to people directly involved in selling to customers.  

[Don’t confuse CAC (Customer Acquisition Cost) with COGS (Cost of Goods Sold) – they are related and may essentially be the same in a simple software business but CAC is the important consideration in our unit economics analysis.]


Lemonade Stand FlyerOur Lemonade Stand

Let’s say we print fliers to advertise our lemonade stand.

These cost $1 each to print and each one brings 10 customers to our stand.

Our Customer Acquisition Cost (CAC) is $0.10 [$1 / 10].

 


LTV

Our next TLA is “LTV” or Life-Time Value.  This refers to how much money you’ll make from each customer, on average, during their entire time being your customer.

LTV is often difficult for startups – especially in the early stages – because you don’t have enough data.  For example, perhaps customers will stay on average 2 years or 10 years but, if the startup is only 18 months old, you don’t know yet.

However, as the company ages, you’ll start to see the average customer life-time level off (or “asymptote”) to a certain value.

A complication here is that LTV can either be discussed as “Gross LTV” which is simply the money you get paid by the customer, or “Net LTV” where the variable costs have been subtracted.  

Net LTV will typically be much lower than Gross LTV.  If you want to look good, use Gross LTV.  If you want to really understand your Unit Economics, use Net LTV.


Lemonade standOur Lemonade Stand 

We’re going to charge 25 cents for a cup of lemonade.  Our stand is only open for 1 month during the summer (and only this year).

On average, each customer buys 4 cups of lemonade. Therefore our customer LTV is $1 [4 x $0.25].

 

 


LTV:CAC Ratio

By dividing the average Lifetime Value (LTV) of a customer by the average cost to acquire a customer (CAC), we get the LTV:CAC ratio.  

This is a simple measure of the efficiency of our business model – it measures how much more money you get back from each customer versus the cost to get the customer.


Lemonade standOur Lemonade Stand

So, our LTV is $1.00, and our CAC is $0.10, so our LTV:CAC ratio is 10:1.  Pretty good.

 

 

 

 


MRR

Our third TLA is “MRR” or Monthly Recurring Revenue.  This is the average amount of money you get each month, from each customer.

MRR is very commonly used for SaaS companies since they tend to have fixed and predictable income from each customer, based on monthly billing of a fixed amount.  e.g. $9.99/month, paid every month until you cancel the service.

As we’ll see later, marketplaces can have very different dynamics and MRR can be a much less useful measure.  I’m including it here because it is very commonly used in the context of unit economics and provides a simple way to explain some of the following concepts.

Break-even Point

As discussed above, the LTV:CAC ratio provides a simple way to understand the efficiency of a business model by comparing the money you make from each customer against how much money it costs to get them.

However, LTV:CAC ignores the time dimension:  in many cases, you bear your CAC upfront but you only receive payment from the customer over time.

The Break-even Point refers to how long it takes a customer to “pay back” what it cost you to acquire them (the CAC).

This chart shows a simple example of a company with a $500 upfront CAC and a fixed $50/month MRR.  (i.e. a customer costs you $500 to acquire and pays you $50 per month for your services.)

Break-even Point

As you can see, it takes 10 months to break-even in this simple case [$500 / $50].

Break-even Point is important because it determines how fast you can grow your business.  While you’re waiting for a customer to “pay back” their CAC, you can’t use that same money to do anything else, like acquire more customers.  (In finance terms, it impacts your “working capital”.)

So, the shorter your Break-even, the better.

CAC-doubling Time

Once you break-even on a customer, you’ve got your money back, and you can rinse-and-repeat.  However, while you’re waiting to get your money back, your speed of growth is limited – you can’t grow any faster without more working capital.

One way to get more working capital is to raise more money from investors.  With this money, you can spend it on acquiring more customers while you’re still waiting for your earlier customers to pay back their CAC.  

The downside of this from a founder’s point of view is that you have to sell part of your company to raise more money, of course.  The downside from an investor’s perspective is that they will have to keep putting more money in to increase the rate that you grow.

Therefore, it’s good to understand the CAC-doubling Point.  This is the point in time where you’ve not only recouped the original CAC, but also earned enough to acquire another customer – i.e. 2x the CAC.  Once you’ve got 2x your CAC back, you can continue to accelerate your growth without having to raise any more money from investors.

Simply put:  your CAC-doubling point tells you how quickly one customer pays you enough to acquire another customer.

Churn

One of the biggest limitations on customer life-time value (LTV) is typically churn – i.e. losing customers.

To understand the impact of churn on your Unit Economics, you need to understand how frequently you lose customers (churn rate) and how much money they’ve spent with you on average before you lose them. 

If they churn before paying back what it cost to acquire them (CAC), then you’re going to lose money – your unit economics are negative and the more you spend to acquire customers, the more money you lose.

Customer Churn

Marginal Operating Costs

Often there are ongoing costs associated with servicing a customer after you’ve paid your CAC to acquire them.  Typical examples would be support and service/maintenance costs.  Such costs are referred to as “Marginal Operating Costs”.

This is an area where finance conventions can differ but it’s easiest to think of Marginal Operating Costs as Variable Costs that occur over time.

From the perspective of Unit Economics, it’s important to understand the impact of Marginal Operating Costs on your Break-even Point.

The below chart shows the same $500 upfront CAC and $50 MRR but, this time, we’re adding a $20 marginal operating cost each month. 

Marginal Operating Costs

As you can see this pushes back the Break-even Point from 10 months to about 17 months. [$500 / ($50 – $20)]

Contribution Margin

Our final basic Unit Economics term is “Contribution Margin”.  This refers to how much of the company’s fixed costs are covered by the revenue from customers, once the variable costs have been taken out.

Personally, I find the term confusing in the context of startups.

“Contribution Margin” is the contribution (hence the name) of a single product towards the company’s overall margin, whereas terms like “Gross Margin” refer to the company as a whole. i.e. if you sell only one product (like most startups), contribution margin and gross margin are essentially equivalent.

Contribution Margin is most often discussed as a ratio – “Contribution Margin Ratio”.  It is simply the revenue divided by the revenue minus variable costs.  Again, if you have one product only, “Contribution Margin Ratio” is equivalent to the % margin for the business as a whole.

Going Beyond Unit Economics

The ultimate objective is that, over time, your Contribution Margin (or margins, if you have more than one product) will be enough to cover all of your Fixed Costs.  

At this point, you can think of your business as “profitable” as a whole, in colloquial terms – enough money is coming in to cover all of your costs (variable and fixed).  In accounting terms, we’d also need to consider any costs related to taxes, interest on loans, etc before we can call it truly “profitable”.

Scooter unit economics: a Cautionary Tale

Now let’s take a look at a cautionary example in recent history.

In 2018, rental scooters suddenly appeared on our streets.  Bird, for example, raised a $100M Series B and a $300M Series C – both in 2018.

Bird Scooters

So, scooter rental must be a great business, with great unit economics, right?

Let’s look at the unit economics of scooters:

  • Acquiring customers was not hard – people were literally tripping over them on the sidewalk (and complaining about it).  So, for the purposes of this analysis, let’s say rider CAC was essentially $0.
  • It cost about $500 to buy one of those first-generation scooters.
  • Each scooter made about $500 per month in revenue.
  • The Marginal Operating Costs – charging, relocating scooters, etc – were about $200 per month.

So a Contribution of Margin of about $300 per month, per scooter.  You can pay back that $500 purchase cost in less than 2 months. Pretty good business?

Bird Scooter destroyed

You may remember what happened:  people didn’t treat the scooters kindly. The average scooter lasted about 28 days, so it wasn’t possible to recover the $500 upfront purchase cost before the scooter was destroyed, and the unit economics didn’t work. 

The other thing that happened was injuries and subsequent lawsuits.  A big proportion of scooter injuries were nasty head injuries, meaning big payouts for the scooter companies.

The huge amount of investment the scooter companies garnered was enough to maintain these losses for a while but ultimately a few things happened:

  • Scooter companies tried to source more resilient scooters, with higher longevity to get to breakeven on each scooter (compare how solid current [2020] scooters are with the first-generation 2017 Bird scooter).
  • Uber/Lyft acquired scooter companies – although the unit economics of scooters were poor, they provided a great way for ride sharing companies to acquire riders, and more cheaply.  By becoming scooter chargers, it also allowed Uber and Lyft to offer additional income generation for their drivers.
  • Some scooter companies pivoted to electric bikes – much lower injury rate, much higher longevity, and much better unit economics.

The lesson of this story is that initial, quick takes on businesses can be misleading – you need to truly understand the unit economics.

Summary so Far

To recap, the core concepts we covered are:

  • Fixed vs Variable Costs
  • Customer Acquisition Cost (CAC)
  • Life Time Value (LTV)
  • LTV:CAC ratio
  • Break-even Point and CAC-doubling Time
  • Churn
  • Marginal Operating Costs
  • Contribution Margin

Next, on to Part II:  Unit Economics in Two-Sided Marketplaces…

Marketplaces: Scaling with Operations vs Engineering?

There are many things that make building and scaling marketplace businesses hard: for example, there’s the quintessential chicken-and-egg problem of building and balancing supply and demand, and there’s the need to build two or more products in parallel to serve the needs of the different participants in your marketplace.

There is also the question of how you scale your marketplace once you’ve got product-market fit established and some unit economics that seem to work.

Electrons vs Atoms

Most marketplaces have to deal with the tangible, real world: unlike pure software/SaaS companies, marketplaces have to deal with whole atoms, rather than just electrons.

Those atoms might make up people, or cars, or meals, or apartments but they are physical resources that have to be managed. This is why marketplaces tend to need significant operational headcount.

However, most marketplace companies aspire to be, and actively position themselves as, technology platform companies.  This of course requires an ongoing investment in product/engineering.

Given finite resources, how do you choose between scaling a market place through operation headcount versus product/engineering investment?  How do you strike the right balance?

The Comparables

I did some quick research to look at what other marketplace businesses are doing.

I took a basket of marketplace companies at varying funding stages and looked at their employee counts on LinkedIn by role.

Firstly, let’s set the scene by looking at the absolute number of engineers that various marketplaces have and compare that to their funding stage:

Perhaps no surprises here: as marketplaces develop, they hire more engineers. I am struck, though, by the widely varying number of engineers that the earlier stages marketplaces seem to have.

Now let’s look at the ratio between operational headcount and engineering headcount in these same companies:

This is also what you might expect.  Although the data is noisy*, it seems that as marketplaces grow, they become less dependent on operational headcount. Presumably, their investments in product/engineering payoff in terms of automations and efficiencies.

Of course there’s also survivorship bias here – these are only the marketplaces that are still around. Perhaps the ones that didn’t make it had wildly different ratios.

What would be great is to get historical data on these ratios and see how that correlates with outcomes. Unfortunately, I don’t have that data (if you do, let me know!).

My bet would be that a higher ratio of operational to engineering headcount is hard for marketplaces to wean themselves off – i.e. it’s hard to change the ratio over time.  If you organization gets accustomed to scaling and solving problems by hiring ops people rather than hiring engineers to automate, that just gets amplified over time.

* my methodology here was simply to search on LinkedIn for people with “engineer” and people with “operations” in their job title. This is obviously error prone for a number of reasons.  For example, some “engineering” roles have “operations” in their job titles, and not all headcount are necessarily on LinkedIn, especially if a company outsources or off-shores some functions. However, given a sufficiently large sample set, one would hope that these effects blend out.

Brute Force Growth vs Long-term Value

Like any business, marketplaces have to continue to show top-line revenue growth in order to maintain the faith of investors and employees and be able to continue to raise money.  The first, second, and third rules of business are “don’t run out of money“.

However, while it’s possible to “brute force” growth of many marketplaces through reliance on operational headcount in the short to medium-term, I believe this strategy has large associated dangers in the longer term.

In a perfect world, you could scale both operational and product/engineering headcount as needed but, in reality, you will be forced to choose between spending each $1 on one or the other. Here’s my quick take on the pros and cons:

In summary, the biggest danger with scaling by adding operational headcount is that it works…in the short-term.  It’s also cheaper.  But, the danger is that you win the battle but not the war.

Agree or disagree, please leave a comment.

Are you confusing Optimization with Growth?

Are you confusing Optimization with Growth?

In a startup, there are always many things that aren’t working as efficiently as they could be – acquisition funnel conversion, manual processes, customer acquisition costs, etc.  This may be incredibly frustrating, especially for the team members who have to deal with it on a day-to-day basis.

It’s very tempting to direct precious money, time, and energy to resolving these frustrations, especially as its your team’s tired faces that you have to look at every day.  It’s always tempting to give the squeaky wheel some oil.

However, it’s vital that you remain focused on growth and don’t confuse growth with optimization. Burning lots of time optimizing at the expense of growing is not a recipe for success for early- to mid-stage, venture-backed startups.

Of course, there is some nuance here: if things are so broken that your team starts to leave, you have to address that – no team; no company.

Also, the smart investors (i.e. the ones you want) realize that, if your unit economics fundamentally don’t work, you will simply lose more money as you grow.

However, conversely, it’s unlikely that a Tier 1 investor will invest in the also-ran, #3 player in any category in terms of growth rate and/or absolute revenue, however optimized and healthy the acquisition funnels, gross margins, etc. Investors are in the business of selecting for the biggest return on their capital, not the best run or most efficient business.  The biggest return comes from the biggest exit and the biggest exit goes to the category winners.

As a venture-backed startup, the most important thing is to stay as one of the leaders in your category – this is what allows you to maintain team confidence and morale, attract the best talent and investors, and continue to raise money when you need it.  Note: there are usually only 1 or 2 “leaders” in any category.

Let’s take two startups:  to start with, Company A and Company B are neck-and-neck.  Both have a $5M in gross revenue, with a average revenue of $5,000 per customer per year and a customer acquisition cost (CAC) of $2,000.  Both have revenue that is doubling each year.  Both are mid-stage startups – they’re not yet profitable and don’t expect to be any time soon.

Both companies also know that their CAC is too high and, by some optimizations, the CAC can be reduced significantly.  The high CAC drives some members of the team crazy – so many opportunities lost, so many wasted marketing dollars.

So, the CEO of Company A directs the team to work on CAC.  Over 6 months, they manage to effect a series of changes process and product changes in their customer-acquisition funnel, through A/B testing, cost reduction, etc.  These compound and end up halving the CAC to $1,000 – that’s a huge improvement.  Company A’s gross margin has significantly improved.

Meanwhile, the CEO of Company B ignores the CAC for now and instead directs the team to focus on increasing the size of the sales and marketing teams significantly and filling the top of the sales funnel with as many leads as possible.

One year later, Company A’s revenue has doubled again and they’re netting an average of $4,000 per customer per year – 33% more.  Not bad.

However, by focusing on growth, one year later, Company B’s revenue has tripled rather than just doubling.  They still net an average of $3,000 per customer per year but there are 3 times more customers.

Both Company A and Company B need to raise more money.  So does a 3rd player in the category; Company C.  Company C is going gang-busters, beating both Company A and Company B on growth rate and total revenue.

You know how this story ends:  Company B and Company C are able to raise giant C-rounds from Tier 1 investors at great valuations.  Meanwhile, Company A has fallen behind – its unit economics are better than Company B’s but it’s now an also-ran and struggles to raise money.  Without that money, it cannot continue to grow and falls further and further behind Company B and Company C.  Perhaps it’s acquired by Company C at a fire-sale valuation or perhaps it’s a giant smoking crater.

Of course, this is a contrived story.  In reality, you can probably achieve growth and some optimization in parallel.  But, the key is not to confuse one with the other.

So, grow and optimize as you go, as long as that optimization doesn’t slow your growth.  Don’t optimize hoping that it will deliver meaningful growth.

tl;dr – in a startup, you can’t optimize your way to success – you must out-grow your competitors.